ZME Science
No Result
View All Result
ZME Science
No Result
View All Result
ZME Science

Home → Science → News

New game theory model explains why people help distant kin

Even though you shouldn't care about helping your third cousin from Wisconsin, chances have it you'll do. Now, there's a new game theory model that explains why this happens.

Tibi PuiubyTibi Puiu
June 16, 2016
in News
A A
Share on FacebookShare on TwitterSubmit to Reddit

It’s a well-established fact that natural selection favors inter-kin cooperation. If you help your sister or cousin when they’re in need, this will increase the chances your gene pool will get passed on. Yet, natural selection shouldn’t favor the aid of distant kin, so why do we do it? A new mathematical framework developed by Doug Jones,  a University of Utah anthropologist, takes into account  “socially enforced nepotism” to account for the disparity between what the theory says and what really happens.

Douglas Jones, associate professor of anthropology at the University of Utah, made a new model to explain why you care helping your third cousin. Credit: Lee J. Siegel, University of Utah
Douglas Jones, associate professor of anthropology at the University of Utah, made a new model to explain why you care helping your third cousin. Credit: Lee J. Siegel, University of Utah

“Socially enforced nepotism” is a fancy way of saying society pressures us to be kind with our distant relatives because that’s how the rules work, despite there’s no genetic payoff. In other words, there’s a genetic and moral dimension to our decision-making as far as helping other people is concerned.

Classic kin-selection theory is based on a famous game theory formula called Hamilton’s rule. In short, this formula specifies the conditions under which reproductive altruism evolved:

r × B > C;

Where B is the benefit (in number of offspring equivalents) gained by the recipient of the altruism, C is the cost (in number of offspring equivalents) suffered by the donor while undertaking the altruistic behaviour, and r is the genetic relatedness of the altruist to the beneficiary. From this equation, it’s clear that as you stray away from your own gene pool the costs outweigh the benefits.

What Jones set out was to prove that Hamilton’s rule can be overridden if we also account for the reputation benefit gained from helping a distant kin.

“Two brothers have a chance to help a third brother,” he says. “If the two decide independently of one another whether to help, Hamilton’s rule applies. But if one approaches the other with an offer, ‘I’ll give extra help if you do too,’ then the level of altruism toward kin may be higher than the simple version of Hamilton’s rule predicts,” Jones said, referring to his earlier work on the Brothers Karamazov Game, based on the novel with the same name.

For his study, Jones devised a model then ran simulations with the numbers of players ranging from ten to hundreds, each of variable ability to help. In these games, various virtual actors “choose different strategies and get payoffs depending on what strategies they choose and what strategies other people choose,” Jones wrote in his paper published in the journal PLOS ONE.

RelatedPosts

Generosity linked with happiness and evolutionary success
Bacteria wouldn’t go for a swine flu shot
How motivation influences cooperation: would you open the ‘envelope’?
Humans are wired to be good in nature – cooperation outweighs selfishness

In the simulation, people would value two rules as follow:

  • “Almost-balanced reciprocity, where you help other people only a much as they help you.”
  •  “Generalized reciprocity, where you might be very helpful even to someone with no ability to pay you back because other people see this, they like what they see, it boosts your reputation and they reward you for it.”

“Both rules are floating around and you see how they compete with each other in a simulation,” Jones says. “Some people follow almost-balanced reciprocity, some people follow generalized reciprocity and some compromise. Some players are really strong and can easily help other people, and others are weak and cannot.”

After running multiple simulations for a wide range of values, Jones came to the conclusion that those players who went for generalized reciprocity came out as winners in the grand evolutionary game.

“If you’re helping distant relatives and they’re not paying you back, then all the balanced reciprocity guys [those expecting return payment for help] are looking at you and saying, ‘What a loser,'” Jones says. But if you help others and expect something in return part of the time and not at other times, “then you do better evolutionarily.”

Jones’ study notes: “Some anthropologists argue that human kinship, insofar as it is socially enforced, is divorced from biology. The argument here, on the contrary, is that kinship is uniquely elaborate and important in our species because norms that push people to treat distant kin like close kin have been favored by natural selection.”

 

Tags: game theory

ShareTweetShare
Tibi Puiu

Tibi Puiu

Tibi is a science journalist and co-founder of ZME Science. He writes mainly about emerging tech, physics, climate, and space. In his spare time, Tibi likes to make weird music on his computer and groom felines. He has a B.Sc in mechanical engineering and an M.Sc in renewable energy systems.

Related Posts

Economics

According to a new study, there are four kinds of people

byMihai Andrei
9 years ago
theresa-sean-penn-zmescience
Mathematics

How motivation influences cooperation: would you open the ‘envelope’?

byTibi Puiu
10 years ago
Biology

Generosity linked with happiness and evolutionary success

byMihai Andrei
12 years ago
Prisoner's Dilemma
Psychology

When the “prisoner’s dillema” is played with real prisoners: unexpected results

byTibi Puiu
12 years ago

Recent news

The Worm That Outsourced Locomotion to Its (Many) Butts

May 16, 2025

The unusual world of Roman Collegia — or how to start a company in Ancient Rome

May 16, 2025
Merton College, University of Oxford. Located in Oxford, Oxfordshire, England, UK. Original public domain image from Wikimedia Commons

For over 500 years, Oxford graduates pledged to hate Henry Symeonis. So, who is he?

May 16, 2025
  • About
  • Advertise
  • Editorial Policy
  • Privacy Policy and Terms of Use
  • How we review products
  • Contact

© 2007-2025 ZME Science - Not exactly rocket science. All Rights Reserved.

No Result
View All Result
  • Science News
  • Environment
  • Health
  • Space
  • Future
  • Features
    • Natural Sciences
    • Physics
      • Matter and Energy
      • Quantum Mechanics
      • Thermodynamics
    • Chemistry
      • Periodic Table
      • Applied Chemistry
      • Materials
      • Physical Chemistry
    • Biology
      • Anatomy
      • Biochemistry
      • Ecology
      • Genetics
      • Microbiology
      • Plants and Fungi
    • Geology and Paleontology
      • Planet Earth
      • Earth Dynamics
      • Rocks and Minerals
      • Volcanoes
      • Dinosaurs
      • Fossils
    • Animals
      • Mammals
      • Birds
      • Fish
      • Amphibians
      • Reptiles
      • Invertebrates
      • Pets
      • Conservation
      • Animal facts
    • Climate and Weather
      • Climate change
      • Weather and atmosphere
    • Health
      • Drugs
      • Diseases and Conditions
      • Human Body
      • Mind and Brain
      • Food and Nutrition
      • Wellness
    • History and Humanities
      • Anthropology
      • Archaeology
      • History
      • Economics
      • People
      • Sociology
    • Space & Astronomy
      • The Solar System
      • Sun
      • The Moon
      • Planets
      • Asteroids, meteors & comets
      • Astronomy
      • Astrophysics
      • Cosmology
      • Exoplanets & Alien Life
      • Spaceflight and Exploration
    • Technology
      • Computer Science & IT
      • Engineering
      • Inventions
      • Sustainability
      • Renewable Energy
      • Green Living
    • Culture
    • Resources
  • Videos
  • Reviews
  • About Us
    • About
    • The Team
    • Advertise
    • Contribute
    • Editorial policy
    • Privacy Policy
    • Contact

© 2007-2025 ZME Science - Not exactly rocket science. All Rights Reserved.